甲沟炎属于什么科| 老年人喝什么蛋白粉好| 龙抬头是什么意思| 头疼呕吐是什么原因| 八月二十是什么星座| acca是什么专业| 虾青素有什么作用| 肾萎缩吃什么药好| 绝命是什么意思| 女人吃山竹有什么好处| 木安读什么| 宫内孕和宫外孕有什么区别| 什么是浸润性乳腺癌| 别墅是什么意思| 善存什么时间吃比较好| 过年吃什么| 老天爷叫什么名字| pw是什么意思| 52年属什么| 别扭是什么意思| 尿道炎是什么引起的| 试管是什么| 手术后吃什么补品好| 长方形纸能折什么| h型高血压是什么意思| 脚气挂号应该挂什么科| 相声海清是什么意思| 输液葡萄糖有什么作用| 蝙蝠吃什么| 下午5点是什么时辰| 龙脉是什么意思| 机电一体化学什么| 去医院看乳房挂什么科| 朱砂有什么用| 清宫手术后需要注意什么| 口臭吃什么好| 情绪是什么意思| 什么动作可以提高性功能| dtc什么意思| 吃什么促进排便| 电动汽车什么牌子好| 西边五行属什么| 球蛋白偏低是什么意思| 什么牌子的氨糖好| 补中益气丸适合什么人吃| 梦见老宅是什么意思| 女性盆腔炎吃什么药| 喝酒后胃疼吃什么药| 缓刑是什么| 尿路感染吃什么药最好| 流鼻血挂什么科| 腿容易麻是什么原因| 喝酒后呕吐是什么原因| 奶茶妹是什么意思| 共济失调是什么病| 为什么会闪电| 手足口病什么症状| 肾盂是什么意思| 高硼硅是什么材质| 什么是非萎缩性胃炎| headache什么意思| 丝瓜什么人不能吃| 山东特产是什么| 西岳什么山| 什么是高危性行为| 吃什么增强免疫力最快| 玉米和什么不能一起吃| 中邪是什么意思| 凝滞是什么意思| 颈椎酸胀是什么原因| 引流是什么意思| elle是什么档次的牌子| 吃卡培他滨禁止吃什么| 桃子和什么相克| 无水乙醇是什么| 两拐是什么军衔| 粘液阳性是什么意思| 捧杀是什么意思| 生物技术专业学什么| 南京市长是什么级别| 玉对人身体健康有什么好处| 长期湿热会引起什么病| 二球是什么意思| 为什么健身后体重反而重了| 布加综合征是什么病| 结界是什么意思| 月经量多是什么原因导致的| 食禄痣是什么意思| 运交华盖是什么意思| 有机什么意思| 男人额头凹陷预示什么| 麦粒肿用什么药| 伤口溃烂不愈合用什么药| 阿莫西林治什么| 人参果吃了有什么好处| 反应蛋白高是什么意思| 大便里急后重什么意思| 尿隐血弱阳性什么意思| 医院脱毛挂什么科| 胃酸过多吃什么好| davena手表什么牌子| 什么叫指标到校| 女上位什么意思| 什么运动可以瘦脸| 份量是什么意思| 水果的英文是什么| 口气重是什么原因| 角逐是什么意思| 吃什么水果祛斑最快| 白细胞低说明什么| 什么是居间费| forever21是什么牌子| 钴对人体有什么伤害| 荨麻疹是什么原因引起的| 3月14日是什么日子| 医院体检挂什么科| 万加一笔是什么字| 颠茄片是什么药| 生酮是什么意思| 甲状腺有什么作用| 女人更年期吃什么药调理最好| 艾绒是什么| 不劳而获是什么意思| 属鼠的是什么命| 1110是什么星座| 拉肚子可以吃什么药| 宫颈潴留性囊肿是什么| 广藿香是什么味道| 什么花是红色的| 优生优育检查什么项目| 左侧肋骨下面是什么器官| 娇兰属于什么档次| 吃什么不长肉| futa是什么意思| 化学键是什么| 县纪委副书记什么级别| 胆固醇高吃什么可以降下来| 胃黏膜受损是什么症状| camouflage什么意思| 捉代表什么生肖| 什么品牌的空气炸锅好| 脸色蜡黄是什么原因| 老犯困是什么原因| 塞药塞到什么位置| 八月十五是什么节日| 阴道炎什么症状| 压差小是什么原因引起的| 孕妇的尿液有什么用途| 槟榔是什么味道的| 吃红苋菜有什么好处| 不可思议的意思是什么| M3什么意思| 荔枝不能和什么一起吃| 1.30是什么星座| 射精什么感觉| 胃胀是什么感觉| 贫血喝什么口服液| 夜尿次数多是什么原因| 一个火一个华念什么| 紧张吃什么药| 避孕药什么牌子好| 脚趾头麻木是什么原因| 什么是心悸有什么症状| 吃什么能降血压| 牛肉烧什么菜好吃| 金牛属于什么象星座| 植物纤维是什么面料| 梦见好多蚊子是什么意思| 脚底有痣代表什么| 口苦吃什么药好| 什么是调剂| 弥漫性病变是什么意思| 盆底肌松弛有什么影响| 骶髂关节炎吃什么药| 倒挂金钩什么意思| 菊花茶和枸杞一起泡水有什么好处| 丁克族是什么意思| 胃反酸吃什么药| 低氧血症是什么意思| 揍是什么意思| 女性吃什么降低雄激素| 爱是什么偏旁| 什么的旋律| 为什么作什么的成语| 5月17日是什么星座| 拉美人是什么人种| 梦见吃梨是什么意思| 为什么养鱼双数是大忌| 地支是什么意思| 美的不可方物什么意思| 身体容易青紫是什么原因| 大便呈绿色是什么原因| 狗是什么属性| 胃在什么位置图片| 奔跑吧什么时候更新| 儿童上火了吃什么降火最快| 血糖高是什么症状| 双马尾是什么意思| 痔疮的克星是什么| 沙僧是什么生肖| chocker是什么| 唐卡是什么| 结肠憩室是什么意思| 总是睡不着觉是什么原因| 静脉曲张吃什么药好| 25是什么生肖| 葛根和什么搭配泡水好| 张宇的老婆叫什么名字| 化疗为什么要剃光头| 坐月子什么不能吃| 额头长痘是什么原因| 为什么怀孕会孕酮低| 清热去火吃什么药| 法国的货币叫什么| 十二生肖它第一是什么生肖| 什么叫环比| 文化内涵是什么意思| kerry英文名什么意思| 党内警告处分有什么影响| 6月1日是什么星座| 代价是什么意思| 甲功三项能查出什么病| 前列腺按摩什么感觉| 老鼠爱吃什么食物| 国医堂是什么意思| 眼睛疲劳用什么眼药水| 鼻子两侧毛孔粗大是什么原因造成的| 为什么一进去就想射| 元朝是什么民族| 1975年属兔是什么命| 表头是什么| 保妇康栓是治疗什么的| 我想成为一个什么样的人| 逍遥丸的功效和作用是什么| 做梦梦到鸡是什么意思| 雪球是什么| 血糖高能吃什么水果| 胃痛去药店买什么药| 掉头发缺少什么维生素| 身上长湿疹是什么原因导致| 红红火火是什么意思| 早上口干苦是什么原因| 过度什么意思| 木槿花的花语是什么| 筋疼挂什么科| 2月24日是什么星座| 支原体感染是什么意思| 高胆固醇血症是什么病| 梦见大火烧山是什么意思| 禁的部首是什么| 单核细胞比率偏高是什么意思| 男方派去接亲要说什么| 脚腿肿是什么原因引起的| kg什么意思| ups是什么快递| 78岁属什么生肖| 曙光是什么意思| 三八妇女节送老婆什么礼物好| 面肌痉挛是什么原因引起的| 冲奶粉用什么水比较好| 什么病不能吃松花粉| 腹泻不能吃什么食物| 风湿看什么科室| 便秘吃什么药好| 百度Jump to content

《芳华》等获导演协会2017年度奖提名

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
百度 就在WE夺得IPL5冠军当天,《英雄联盟》发布了一个名为服务器争霸赛的线上比赛,其目的在于从广泛的玩家群体当中,选拔优秀队伍,参与到职业级联赛的角逐当中。

Costly signaling theory in evolutionary psychology refers to uses of costly signaling theory and adaptationism in explanations for psychological traits and states. Often informed by the closely related fields of human behavioral ecology and cultural evolution, such explanations are predominantly focused on humans and emphasize the benefits of altering the perceptions of others and the need to do so in ways that are difficult to fake due to the widespread existence of adaptations which demand reliable information to avoid manipulation through dishonest signals.[1]

Although initially created to explain costly morphological traits as honest signals of an individual's underlying quality resulting from sexual selection,[2] the scope of costly signaling theory has been expanded to include signals of cooperative intent and need,[3][4] with the targets of such signals often going beyond potential mates.[3]

Costly signaling background

[edit]

Almost any organism can benefit from altering the perceptions, behavior, and physiology of others in its environment in ways that favor itself.[5][6][7] Particularly true in social species, the result is often investment in signals to enhance one’s perceived attractiveness, formidability, or cooperative value to members of their own species.[6][8]

A signal differs from a cue in that signals evolved to influence the behavior or perceptions of others, while a cue is any piece of information an organism uses to alter its current state that was not created for this purpose.[9] As signals evolve due to their communicative effects and are often not fully linked to the qualities being signaled, they have the potential to be easily faked by those who do not possess a trait.[2] Such faking would likely be favored through natural selection due to the ubiquity of conflicts of interests among living things creating situations in which the negative impacts on others are either not relevant or still worth the benefits to the signaler.[10]

Although there are substantial risks of being deceived, targets of a signal may still benefit from paying attention to this information as long as it is honest and relevant to fitness-related problems.[11][12] For this reason, natural selection is thought to have resulted in adaptations in many species to verify the validity of signals before accepting the information as reliable.[1][13][14][15] Signaling in a costly manner is thought to satisfy these anti-manipulation adaptations when the resultant signals are comparatively cheaper to produce for those who have the underlying quality compared to those who lack it.[11] In these instances, individuals with the quality can maximize their fitness by investing more in the signal relative to those who lack the quality or possess it to a lesser degree, thereby resulting in a signal that, while often not impossible to fake, tends to not be worth faking.[16]

Costly signals of beneficial qualities

[edit]

The majority of costly signaling explanations involve behaviors that broadcast beneficial traits about oneself to others.[17] In many instances, these signals are expected to be directed towards potential mates, with males often thought to benefit more from such signaling due to their relatively low levels of investment in offspring leading to greater fitness benefits in having multiple partners.[18][19][20] However, the importance of cooperation over human evolutionary history is also thought to have resulted in many signals that involve showing one’s potential as a cooperative partner to those outside of mates.[8][3]

Costly signals of embodied capital

[edit]

Hunting

[edit]

Primarily through the work of human behavioral ecologists, hunting among humans has received much attention as potentially serving as an honest indicator of various qualities due to its potential for differential costs.[12][20][21][22][23] The first signaling approaches to hunting emphasized that although hunting can provide an important source of calories and nutrients in small-scale societies, it is still practiced when it is less efficient than other means of food production and often involves the targeting of species that result in less meat for a given period.[20][22][24] In response to this and findings that food is typically shared widely in small-scale societies, the show-off hypothesis suggests that men may hunt difficult prey in part due to reputational benefits that increase the likelihood that others will want good hunters in their group because of the benefits they provide.[24]

Later models built off this by incorporating costly signaling theory.[20][25] In addition to the costs of inefficiency reported in some hunts, hunting can be costly in terms of the time needed to develop one’s skill, the risks involved, and the resources required for a successful hunt.[21] For this reason, it has been proposed to honestly signal a wide range of traits including strength, skill, ability to buffer risk, leadership, and various beneficial cognitive traits, all of which can increase one’s attractiveness to mates and cooperative partners.[21][25][26] As with other costly signals, this is due to hunting being relatively more costly for those who lack the previously mentioned qualities or possess them to a lesser degree, with such individuals being more likely to produce less effective signals and become injured, both of which deter faking the signal.[21]

Although not mutually exclusive with the show-off hypothesis, such approaches have been presented as explaining a wider range of hunting behaviors as the benefits that come with signaling one’s qualities does not require that hunting benefits others, thereby better accounting for relatively wasteful displays.[21] However, these models still emphasize the benefits of providing for others as meat sharing is often public and attracts large audiences, thereby increasing the effectiveness of a signal to increase one’s status within a group.[21][22]

Evidence in favor of hunting being a costly signal of beneficial qualities has primarily come from its valuation by group members and by the benefits good hunters enjoy. In small-scale societies, individuals can often tell a good hunter from a bad one,[21] with skilled hunters having been reported as having higher status than those less skilled.[22][26] Material benefits are also seen with good hunters having been shown to have increased reproductive success, more political power, and more support for one’s kin in both times of illness and health.[20][22][27]

Compared to the existence of the reputational benefits of hunting, its importance in explaining human hunting relative to explanations involving kin selection or reciprocity is more controversial. This is primarily seen through disagreement on the amount of provisioning that happens within a family and the general ability of hunters to control who receives the meat they bring in.[25]

Risk-taking

[edit]

Often invoked in costly signaling approaches to hunting, risk-taking has been suggested to result in honest signals of quality in other forms.[28][29][30][31] As risk increases, so do the costs that come with failure.[28] This results in greater costs for those who do not have qualities which allow for greater chances of success or the ability to buffer failure relative to those who possess such qualities. For this reason, risky behaviors may often be honest signals, with individuals who lack the relevant traits being expected to avoid risk or suffer too much damage from failures to maintain risky behavior.[28][29]

Many beneficial qualities have been suggested to underlie risk-taking behavior. For example, physical skill, good judgment, or bravery have all been argued to increase the chances of success in risky situations.[28][29] Similarly, social dominance, confidence, and ambition may also help in competition among conspecifics, with social dominance, ambition, and wealth also potentially limiting the costs of failure.[30]

In general, the targets of risky signals are often thought to be potential mates.[20][28][30] This is primarily due to the finding that young males (who are the age and sex class with the highest reproductive variance) take more risks than any other group in both experiments and observational data.[28][30][31] By undertaking risky endeavors, males are thought to signal the previously mentioned qualities which may be directly related to one’s ability to provision and protect one’s family.[29] However, traits like bravery and physical prowess may also be valued by cooperative partners due to their benefits in group-hunting and warfare, thereby increasing the potential audience for risk takers.[29]

Physical attractiveness

[edit]

Physically attractive traits have also been hypothesized to be signals of mate quality, with facial characteristics, body type, voice characteristics, and body modification having all been suggested to provide information relevant to reproduction.[16][32][33][34][35][36] However, most approaches focus on how the information is relevant to the receiver rather than whether the information takes the form of signals or cues,[34][37] with the two possibilities often hard to distinguish between.[38]

Although exceptions exist, costly signaling theory has mainly been incorporated into explanations for attractive male traits in a wide range of species.[32][39][40] In humans, both low voice pitch and facial masculinity in males have been suggested to be honest indicators of male quality due to testosterone’s connection facial and vocal cord development and its hypothesized role in mediating tradeoffs.[35][36] From such perspectives, only high-quality males can afford to invest heavily in phenotypic qualities outside those needed for survival due to lower relative costs of such investment, with testosterone’s linking of these traits with facial and vocal characteristics preventing individuals from faking these signals. Additionally, low voice pitch may also be difficult to fake in the short-term due to activation of the autonomic nervous system, which controls fight-or-flight responses, altering voice pitch.[35] For this reason, only individuals who are confident in their ability are likely ability can afford to maintain low levels of arousal, thereby potentially serving as an honest signal of formidability.

Regardless of whether the information comes from cues or signals, differences are expected in which information is valued by each sex.[38] In general females are expected to be more sensitive to information about the ability of potential mates to acquire and defend resources, while males are expected to focus more on potential partners’ ability to conceive and take care of future children.[16] Outside of these areas, both sexes are often suggested to benefit similarly in signaling pathogen resistance or a lack of harmful mutations due to their hypothesized importance over human evolutionary history.[16][32]

Art

[edit]

Art has also received attention as a costly signal of beneficial qualities relevant to sexual selection.[41][42][43][44] If defined as environmental modification lacking adaptive functions outside of sexual selection, art or art-like behavior has been observed in spiders, crabs, fish, and birds in addition to humans.[44] Unlike the art of other species, however, the form of human art is generally not considered to be genetically encoded.[43] Instead, adaptationist approaches often involve the hypothesis that humans possess adaptations capable of resulting in a wide range of artwork as sexual signals and adaptations for correctly evaluating the information being signaled.

The costs of producing art are expected to increase with the quality of the piece and come in multiple forms. Creating art can require substantial amounts of time to learn the skills involved, find materials, and produce the work, all of which can prevent the individual from investing in other fitness enhancing tasks.[42][43][44] The materials involved may also require substantial resources to obtain and production itself may be physically demanding or risky. Once created, works of art may also require defense against theft or sabotage from potential rivals.[44]

Since these costs are relatively less impactful for those in good condition, producing art is thought to be an honest signal of one’s quality, with those in good condition being able to afford greater investment in art.[42][43][44] For this reason, it may reliably signal information about one’s health, access to resources, or the relative absence of harmful mutations which might negatively impact one’s ability or overall condition. In instances where art needs to be defended, it may also signal one’s formidability and social power.[44]

As a hypothesized form of sexual signaling, males are expected to benefit from using art to signal to larger audiences than females, with evidence of this seen in both humans and non-human animals.[44] However, in humans, the potential for sex differences has been argued to not extend to artistic ability due to the commonality of long-term monogamous relationships resulting in the increased importance of mutual mate choice, something which favors females to invest more in sexual signals relative to other species.

Evidence consistent with art often involving sexual signals in humans primarily comes from studies examining mate preferences. For example, a study examining mating preferences in thirty-seven cultures found that being "creative and artistic" was the sixth most important trait to females and the seventh most important trait to males out of thirteen qualities regarded as attractive.[18][44] Additionally, greater effort towards the creation of public art has been associated with higher numbers of sexual partners among populations of both young adults and artists.[44]

Courtship duration

[edit]

Lengthy courtships have also been proposed to honestly signal one's overall quality, particularly in non-human animals.[45] Although often accompanied by other signals, courtship duration on its own can create substantial opportunity costs as males cannot court other females at this time or invest in other fitness enhancing activities. For this reason, it may be an honest signal of overall quality due to the expectation that low-quality males will suffer more from opportunity costs per unit of time in courtship than high quality males, thereby favoring low quality males to drop out courtship sooner.

In humans, willingness to engage in lengthy courtships has also been suggested to signal desire for a long-term relationship as opposed to casual sex, with there being evidence that persistent courtship styles are more attractive for females seeking long-term relationships than those seeking shorter-term relationships.[46]

Infant crying as a signal of vigor

[edit]

In addition to potentially signaling need or being a means to manipulate parents, crying in human infants has been suggested to serve as a costly signal meant to decrease the child’s risk of infanticide, something which is seen across cultures.[47][48][49][50]

Due to the fact that conflicts of interests exist between an offspring and both its parents and siblings, parents are expected to be sensitive to the quality of their offspring in determining how much investment to provide.[10][47][48][49] As parental investment in one offspring cannot go to another, the potential exists for investment in a new child to reduce an individual’s fitness.[51] This can happen when an offspring is unlikely to survive, thereby favoring investment in other areas.[49] Additionally, such investment may still be costly with high likelihoods of survival if it puts the well-being of other siblings at risk.[48][49] In these situations, older siblings are expected to be favored due to being closer to reproduction and the fact that they have already survived infancy which has higher mortality rates than later childhood.[10][52]

Crying is proposed to help reduce one’s infanticide risk by establishing the perception of vigor in others.[47][48][49] This is primarily thought to be possible due to the energy costs of crying making it costlier for infants in worse condition.[50] For this reason, it may serve as a reliable indicator of what an infant can afford to spend, thereby making it an honest signal of quality.[47][50] Additionally, the acoustic frequency of one's cries may also carry information about one's fitness prospects based on studies which have found correlations between cry pitch and various diseases.[50]

Such an approach has been extended to the excessive crying of colic.[48] However, crying’s connection to need has also been suggested to result in excessive crying being more likely to lead to reduced investment by making offspring appear in worse of condition.[47][52][50]

Academic publishing

[edit]

Although not necessarily a signal of the author’s qualities, the costs involved with academic publishing have been suggested to result in honest signaling about the quality of the journal article being submitted under certain conditions.[53]

Academic publishing involves conflicts of interests between authors and journals, with authors benefiting from having articles accepted in high prestige journals regardless of quality and journals benefiting from publishing only articles that meet their standards.[53] When the submission process involves little cost and no differential benefits, the optimal strategy for authors is likely to involve signaling that one’s work is higher quality than it is and submitting all publications to high-impact journals before submitting them to lower-impact journals, even when the probability of acceptance is low.

One way for honest signaling to arise in academic publishing is if the costs involved differ based on the quality of the paper.[53] This is possible when submitting a low-quality paper to a high impact journal results in a lengthier peer review process, requires greater time to give the paper the appearance of being higher quality, or necessitates payments for resubmission. As these costs are experienced to a greater degree when submitting low-quality papers, their existence may favor honest communication and submission to journals that match the quality of the paper.

Costly signals of cooperative intent

[edit]

Outside of mating contexts in which there is little to gain through the provisioning or care of offspring, a signal of one's high quality may often not be enough to result in beneficial treatment from others, even when it is honest.[54] Instead, individuals are also expected to pay attention to the likelihood that they will receive benefits before cooperating with another individual.[8][54] This makes signaling one's willingness to provide benefits to others an important part of establishing cooperative relationships, something which is seen in both observational and experimental studies which have found that individuals tend to prefer those who are generous but have less to give as cooperative partners than those who have the ability to provide benefits but often do not.[54]

Public displays of generosity

[edit]

Costly signaling has often been used in attempts to explain instances of public generosity in which individuals incur costs without any immediate benefits.[3] Although often thought to signal one's ability to provide benefits, such behaviors have also been considered as honest signals of one’s willingness to cooperate due to the costs involved.

Food sharing
[edit]

Food sharing is often reported to be a common occurrence in many small-scale societies, particularly with hunted game.[24][55] Non-signaling explanations for this have focused on either the benefits of establishing reciprocal relationships with others to buffer risk or the limited benefits of maintaining control over food, due to either the effort required or spoilage in large game.[56][55] However, neither may be mutually exclusive with signaling strategies due to the importance of reputation to cooperative relationships and the fact that sharing food that may not be worth defending still requires the effort to collect in the first place.[55]

Due to its link to food production, food sharing may signal the qualities of the provider in instances when obtaining food results in differential costs based on one’s underlying traits.[12][21][27][55] As with other signals of cooperative intent, it may also signal one's generosity, as such sharing is costlier for those who are likely to defect rather than gain from long-term cooperative relationships.

When seen as a signal of generosity, the type of information signaled is likely to depend on the form of sharing and who receives what.[27] Sharing widely may signal one's intentions of future cooperation with one’s group,[27] while more targeted examples constrained to only a subset of one's group can signal interest in forming cooperative relationships with individuals or coalitions within a group.[54][27] Sharing may also be an effective signal of generosity to those not receiving benefits if it reflects a stable personality trait that varies among individuals.[8]

Competitive feasting
[edit]

Compared to the day to day sharing seen in small-scale societies, the staging of large feasts in which those holding them pay the majority of the costs may also demonstrate cooperative intent, with such practices being found among diverse groups.[57] However, the fact that feasts tend to only happen at particular times of the year and involve competition between groups has been used to suggest that they may primarily be forms of conspicuous consumption meant to signal one's overall quality or status.[57][56]

Blood donations
[edit]

Costly signaling has also been suggested to explain blood donations. In the most common form, individuals give blood voluntary, while receiving no payment and having no control over who gets the donation.[58] This results in a lack of obvious benefits for the donator who also incurs opportunity costs and the risk of mistakes and other negative outcomes, the threat of which may cause anxiety and other forms of psychological distress.

Unlike explanations involving direct reciprocity and kin selection which are suggested to be irrelevant to blood donations due to the lack of control over who receives the blood, signaling explanations allow for benefits to come from one’s ability to alter the perceptions of others in ways that benefit the signaler.[58] This is proposed to involve increased perceptions of generosity and willingness to take risks in addition to providing reliable information about one’s health due to individuals with certain health conditions or diseases not being allowed to donate blood.

Indirect reciprocity
[edit]

Costly signaling may also be involved in many forms of indirect reciprocity.[8][59][57] Indirect reciprocity occurs when one’s seemingly altruistic acts increase one's reputation for cooperation, making others more likely to help regardless of if they were the target of the act.[60] Based on game theoretic models, this can evolve in the absence of signaling through fixed strategies.[59][61] However, in species with the flexibility to alter their level of cooperation in response to their own state and relevant social variables, past behaviors with others may not be enough on their own to reliably signal cooperative intent without the inclusion of other means to ensure the honesty of the signal.[59] When this is the case and a species has the ability to both determine the likelihood others will cooperate and signal their own cooperative intent, costly signaling may be an important mechanism behind indirect reciprocity.[8]

In humans, this has been proposed to take the form of individuals identifying potential targets of signals through the maintenance of welfare-tradeoff ratios and then employing costly signals to increase one’s perceived value as a cooperator to attractive targets for cooperation in the future.[8]

Dyadic gift giving

[edit]

Costly signals have also been suggested to be important for demonstrating commitment to both initiate and maintain dyadic relationships, with gift giving in particular receiving substantial attention as an individual strategy [62][63][64][65] and as a custom.[66]

Such approaches emphasize that the risk of defection from potential friends and romantic partners is particularly high at the start of relationships due to the amount of private information individuals have about their intentions to cooperate.[62] Gifts are thought to help with this when the costs involved are large enough to not be worth providing by someone who does not value the potential for a long-term relationship.[67][62] As the costs of the gift are thought to result in a reliable signal, almost any form of gift could signal future cooperative intent. However, gifts that do not increase the receiver’s fitness prospects may be favored, as those that result in material benefits for the receiver are likely to increase the risk of being manipulated by others.[62][64][65] Similarly, the fact that gifts are often personalized, sex specific, or involve goods that degrade quickly has been suggested to reduce the likelihood that the receiver can benefit from regifting the item with other partners, thereby further reducing the risk of defection.[66]

As a relationship develops, some models emphasize that the costs involved with gift giving should increase to signal greater levels of commitment.[62] Assuming one’s partner reciprocates along the way, this is expected to result in costs that are greater than what would be expected from with a large favor when one is likely to be in need, the time when developed friendships are most vulnerable to defection.

Although the focus is often on signaling one’s desire for a long-term relationship, it is likely not the only quality being signaled.[65] Instead, one’s ability to acquire resources may also be demonstrated in larger gifts. Additionally, individuals may also demonstrate one’s thoughtfulness and attentiveness to a partner by matching the gift to his or her preferences, something which has been proposed to be very difficult to fake.[65][67]

Assuming other individuals in a population behave similarly, gift giving may also reduce the benefits of defection by making it costly to start new relationships,[62]  something which may be particularly likely when gift giving is largely dictated by customs that are inherently costly for those without the intent of future cooperation.[66]

Ritual

[edit]

Costly signaling approaches to ritual often emphasize the ability of ritual behavior to honestly signal commitment to one’s group due to the costs involved resulting in signals that are difficult to fake.[68][69][70][71][72]

Religious rituals have received the most attention as potential costly signals. Like other forms of ritual, the costs involved come from the time, energy, material goods, or physical harm required for one to fit the ritual’s prescriptions,[69] with extreme forms of self-harm not being uncommon.[73] Although the costs of the ritual itself are likely to be equal among believers and nonbelievers, skeptics have been suggested to perceive rituals as more costly due to them not believing in the power of the ritual to achieve what believers expect of it.[69] This difference in perception makes it less likely an individual will find belief worth faking, with costlier practices expected to provide greater indications of one’s commitment. Additionally, the commonality that religious rituals are often complex means that mistakes may be easy to spot throughout the ritual, further decreasing the likelihood of someone faking their commitment.[70][73]

Evidence consistent with costly signaling explanations for religious ritual comes from both experimental and observational studies; however, few examinations exist on the topic.[74] For example, members of religious kibbutzes have been shown to be more cooperative compared to secular kibbutzes in a common-pool resource game.[73][72] Similarly, those engaging in communal religious rituals have been shown to have larger cooperative networks than those who did not participate.[74] Other studies have attempted to more directly link the costs of signals to the effectiveness of cooperation, with one finding the number of costly requirements of a commune to be associated with longer commune lifespan[75] and another finding that participation in and observation of a costly ritual was associated with larger donations compared to those involved with a less costly ritual.[76]

Apology

[edit]

In addition to attempts at creating cooperative relationships, the costly signaling model of apology suggests that costly signals may also be used as a way to restore cooperation after a transgression.[77] Since the costs of honest and dishonest verbal apologies are identical for the individual apologizing and the costs of continued victimization may be severe for the target of the apology, it is unlikely that verbal apologies alone will often be enough to convey contrition. For this reason, costs may be an adaptive part of an apology, increasing the effectiveness of the apology so that the apologizer is more likely to remain in the cooperative venture.

For an apology to be effective, the model does not require costs to be tied to harm caused by the transgression.[77] Instead, the signal only needs to be costly enough to outweigh the benefits a defector could gain in a one-time interaction, thereby creating a situation in which only those who are interested in future cooperation gain net benefits from the signal.

As honesty is established through costs, apologies consistent with the model can take many forms, with financial loss, self-harm, and the reduction of one’s status have all been documented to be associated with apologies to both other individuals and religious deities.[78] Apologies may also include gifts or other benefits; however, the benefits themselves are not predicted to increase the honesty of the signal.[77] Instead, they may simply be one way for the signaler to incur costs.

In addition to less costly forms, non-lethal suicide attempts have also been suggested to serve as honest apologies in some instances.[78] Unlike other forms of costs, the costs of a suicide attempt primarily come from the probability of one’s death, with riskier attempts being seen as costlier.[78][79][80] According to the costly apology model of suicide, such substantial costs may be required to honestly signal contrition when the potential payoff to future defection is large enough to still allow for deceivers to gain net benefits through less costly signals, something which may occur when highly valuable cooperative relationships are in threat of being ended.[78] Suicide attempts may also increase the spread of the information from the signal due to their noteworthy nature, something which may be particularly important when the transgression was made against a group or puts cooperative relationships with those outside the aggrieved at risk.

Evidence for the costly signaling model of apology has mainly come from experiments. For example, multiple vignette studies have found that costly apologies increase the perception of sincerity by the target of the signal across different countries and religions, with the costs of gift giving and self-punishment both being effective.[77][81] Similarly, participants in a study that had them imagine an accidental transgression in the past were more likely to report willingness to engage in a costly apology when an individual was more likely to be important to them.[82] However, costly self-punishment was common in a study which forced participants to accidentally treat an anonymous partner unfairly, something which is consistent with the idea that apologies may also serve to maintain one’s reputation to a larger audience.[83]

Infant-directed song

[edit]

Infant-directed song has been suggested to be a costly signal of parental attentiveness, something which is thought to particularly important when infants are too young to walk or correctly avoid dangers in their environment.[84]

Although parents experience fitness benefits from providing attention to infants and infants can gain fitness benefits from their parents spending time in other tasks, the optimal amount of resources devoted to this is expected to be an example of parent-offspring conflict, with infants benefiting from more attention than what is ideal for the parent. Due to this conflict of interest, infants are expected to be sensitive to information relating to parental attention and come equipped with adaptations help elicit it, something which is proposed to result in selection pressures on parents to better signal their attententiveness.[84]

Infant-directed song is thought to help with this due to its production being costlier to make when the parent is focused on other aspects of its environment, thereby increasing the honesty of the signal.[84] According to this hypothesis, the potential costs of infant-directed song can come in multiple non-exclusive forms. For example, singing may require investment in both planning and memory, while also potentially requiring the parent to attend to the infant’s emotional state and alter the song to match. It may also prevent one from doing physically demanding activities in instances that require specific breathing patterns.

Whatever form the costs take, the benefit to the parent is suggested to be quicker and more reliable satiation of infant demands which would then allow greater for investment in other areas.[84]

Costly signals of wealth

[edit]

As wealth influences one’s access to resources directly and by increasing the status of those who possess it, demonstrations of wealth have been hypothesized to have substantial benefits and often take the form of costly signals.[85] Although wealth alone may be worth signaling, such signals are often suggested to display information about qualities relating to one’s ability to acquire and defend resources in the future.[86] They may also signal generosity when this involves a charitable component; however, this benefit is often considered secondary.[3]

Conspicuous consumption

[edit]

One potential means for signaling wealth is conspicuous consumption. Conspicuous consumption refers to instances when individuals purchase luxury goods which provide little to no utility over less costly versions,[86] thereby prioritizing self-presentation over economic efficiency.[19] It is common across humans regardless of class and often involves strategic planning to maximize the audience of the display and the strength of the signal.[57]

Most signaling explanations of conspicuous consumption predict the targets of the signal will predominately be potential mates.[19][87] As with other signals relating to sexual selection, males are typically expected to invest more in these signals due to the potential for greater benefits through additional matings.[85] In these instances, the information signaled is thought to go beyond genetic quality and signal the potential for investment, which can be attractive to those seeking both long-term and short-term mating strategies.[19][88] Although often focused on males, females have also been suggested to benefit from conspicuous consumption in mating contexts due to its hypothesized ability to demonstrate the commitment of one’s partner[89] and signal one’s mate quality to rivals,[90] both of which may help in intrasexual competition and deter mate poaching.

Despite the focus on sexual selection, conspicuous consumption may also be useful for problems outside of acquiring mates. This can involve attempts at attracting other cooperative partners, who stand to gain from the signalers ability to confer benefits should they form an alliance.[8][57] As in mating contexts, there may also be benefits to intimidating rivals, thereby decreasing the likelihood of direct competition for resources in the future.[90]

Evidence consistent with conspicuous consumption being a costly signal of wealth and status comes from primarily from findings that females find males with more expensive items more desirable. This is mainly seen in experiments which have manipulated the costs of items associated with males, with cars and clothing typical of higher classes having been found to be associated with increased probabilities of females entering into various types of romantic and sexual relationships and greater perceptions of attractiveness across multiple studies.[85]

Outside of its benefits, there has been much less research on whether conspicuous consumption meets the other requirements of being a signal, with it being possible that a mismatch exists between hypothesized adaptations for status signaling and modern environments which include marketing campaigns that might exploit such adaptations.[86] However, its commonality across cultures and class boundaries have been used to argue that humans may be well suited to balancing the costs and benefits of the signal.[86][87]

Public philanthropy

[edit]

Extravagant charitable donations have also been suggested to honestly signal one's wealth due to large donations being impossible or costlier to make for those with fewer resources.[54][57][91] As with conspicuous consumption, such signals are also often expected to provide information about one's underlying quality in addition to wealth, particularly relating to one's ability to acquire and maintain possession of resources.[57]

Due to the qualities signaled and their public nature, public philanthropy has been suggested to mainly serve to attract new cooperators.[54] For this reason, existing cooperators may view such signals as threats to their ongoing relationships, and put more weight on private signals to evaluate the cooperative intent of the signaler. Consistent with this reasoning, public displays of generosity may often decrease one's perceptions of cooperativeness or trustworthiness when they appear to be strategies meant to gain recognition or prestige.[54]

Costly signals of need

[edit]

In addition to signaling qualities meant to increase one’s attractiveness to potential mates or other cooperative partners, costly signals have also been suggested to result in honest displays of need. Primarily aimed at existing cooperators who would be motivated to help given genuine need on the part of the signaler, such signals are hypothesized to reduce doubt surrounding the severity of one’s situation in ways less costly signals could not.[92][80][93]

Depression

[edit]

Due in part to its costs, prevalence, and apparent ability for anyone to develop it, major depression has been hypothesized to often serve as a credible signal need.[4][92] The bargaining model of depression suggests that throughout our evolutionary history individuals would have often faced instances of social adversity (e.g., abuse, the death of an important figure in one’s life, or the end of a romantic relationship) in which their fitness prospects depended primarily on responses from others.[92] In these situations, providing social support could result in benefits for individuals who gain from cooperating with the depressed individual or otherwise benefit from their success. However, the costs involved with providing help and the threat of manipulation require reliable information before sufficient help is likely to be provided.

As with the other proposed costly signals, depression is proposed to achieve this due to the costs involved making the signal prohibitively costly to fake for those who are not in severe enough need.[4][92] The costs of major depression primarily come through the reduction of interest and investment in one’s normal pattern of behavior. Although highly costly to those who are not in need, this does not require substantial costs on the part of an honest signaler. Instead, instances of severe enough adversity can result in a situation in which there is no difference in one’s fitness prospects in being depressed or not, with the costs still being substantial for those not actually in enough need.[92]

In addition to serving as an honest signal of need, the bargaining model also emphasizes depression’s potential role as a bargaining tool.[4][92] This is possible due to the reduction in behavior that often accompanies depression reducing the benefits the depressed individual provides to others. For this reason, many instances of depression are predicted to be analogous to a labor strike in that individuals who previously benefited from the depressed individual receive the message that they need to upregulate their support to once again gain from his or her cooperation.[92]

Illness symptoms

[edit]

Various types of conspicuous illness symptoms have also been suggested to serve as honest signals of need.[93][94] Although much of one’s illness symptoms are likely to come in the form of cues resulting from one’s susceptibilities to a pathogen or byproducts of one's defenses against it, such approaches suggest they may also be upregulated in order to better signal need. As symptoms may be costly in terms of energy, opportunity costs, and reputation, it is expected to be costlier for potential fakers than those who are actually ill and experiencing symptoms already. For this reason, potential fakers are not expected to gain net fitness benefits from such displays, thus increasing the likelihood the targets of one’s signal will believe the individual to be ill and provide meaningful benefits that outweigh the costs of signaling.

Formulated as an explanation for placebo responses, the signaling theory of symptoms predicts that once the signaling function of upregulated symptoms is achieved and others provide support, symptoms will then be downregulated to a level appropriate for disease fighting signaling.[93] In line with this, evidence for the ability to alter one’s symptom levels in response to the presence of conspecifics exists in many species,[94] and placebo responses themselves tend to primarily occur after treatments an individual believe to be efficacious are given.[93] Additionally, placebo responses are often sensitive to the demeanor and behaviors of the care provider, as would be expected with signaling approaches if care providers are seen as potential targets of the signal.[93]

Crying

[edit]

Compared to the other proposed signals of need, crying is the least controversial as having a signaling function. However, it has been argued that there is currently little evidence to distinguish it from a cue with a high degree of confidence, and relatively few signaling explanations involve the costs of crying and how this might lead to honest signaling.[95]

Infant crying as a signal of need

[edit]

The functions of crying are often thought to differ based on whether the crier is an infant or from another age class. In infants, signaling need for food, attention, and protection have been the most commonly proposed functions.[48] As is the case with explanations of crying as a signal of vigor, the primary cost of infant crying is typically thought to be energetic, with such costs having the potential to result in a signal that is costlier to fake than produce when in honest need. This has been used to suggest that the frequency and duration of crying forms an important part of the signal;[48] however, it has also been proposed that the costs underlying crying may also be connected to the sounds produced.[49][96]

Despite the commonality of signaling explanations for infant crying, responses to infants can often be negative in addition to the positive responses predicted.[96][97] In particular, negative responses to crying have been found to be associated with post-partum depression, anxiety, and high levels of neuroticism.[96] However, not all responses are thought to be equally relevant to evaluating whether crying can be an adaptive signal, with negative emotional responses alone not being sufficient evidence of negative fitness outcomes due to the greater importance of behavioral responses.[48]

Adult crying

[edit]

Often expected to involve low costs compared to the other hypothesized costly signals of need,[95][98] the potential costs of adult crying have been proposed to come from diverse areas. For example, crying has been shown to reduce one’s reputation and potentially lead to avoidance in Western societies.[99][100] It may also be connected to lessened immune function based on studies reporting lower levels of salivary Immunoglobulin A in adult women following tears but not sadness alone.[50] Tear production also impedes vision, reducing one’s ability to respond to threats in one’s environment.[95] However, tears may also function to hide information by increasingly the difficulty of others to determine the direction of one’s gaze.

Consistent with signaling explanations, individuals have been shown to respond positively to those crying despite viewing them less favorably and experiencing more negative emotions, although negative responses are also reported.[100][101] Additionally, individuals have been found to report feeling better after crying when social support is present, with crying alone tending to not improve one’s mood as would be predicted with a signaling hypothesis.[100]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ a b Hasson, Oren (2025-08-06). "Cheating Signals". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 167 (3): 223–238. Bibcode:1994JThBi.167..223H. doi:10.1006/jtbi.1994.1065. ISSN 0022-5193.
  2. ^ a b Zahavi, Amotz (2025-08-06). "Mate selection—A selection for a handicap". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 53 (1): 205–214. Bibcode:1975JThBi..53..205Z. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.586.3819. doi:10.1016/0022-5193(75)90111-3. ISSN 0022-5193. PMID 1195756.
  3. ^ a b c d e Barclay, Pat (2025-08-06). "Strategies for cooperation in biological markets, especially for humans". Evolution and Human Behavior. 34 (3): 164–175. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2013.02.002. ISSN 1090-5138.
  4. ^ a b c d Hagen, Edward H (2025-08-06). "The Functions of Postpartum Depression". Evolution and Human Behavior. 20 (5): 325–359. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(99)00016-1. ISSN 1090-5138.
  5. ^ Zahavi, Amotz (1993). "The fallacy of conventional signalling". Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences. 340 (1292): 227–230. Bibcode:1993RSPTB.340..227Z. doi:10.1098/rstb.1993.0061. ISSN 0962-8436. PMID 8101657.
  6. ^ a b Dawkins, Richard (1984). The extended phenotype: the long reach of the gene (Revised ed.). Oxford. ISBN 978-0-19-102434-4. OCLC 864140193.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  7. ^ Krebs, John; Dawkins, Richard (1978). "Animal Signals: Mind-Reading and Manipulation". In Krebs, John; Davies, Nicholas (eds.). Behavioral Ecology: An Evolutionary Approach. Oxford: Blackwell Scientific Publications. ISBN 0632002859.
  8. ^ a b c d e f g h Barclay, Pat (2015). "Reputation". The Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology. American Cancer Society. pp. 1–19. doi:10.1002/9781119125563.evpsych233. ISBN 978-1-119-12556-3.
  9. ^ Smith, Maynard J.; Harper, D. G. C. (2025-08-06). "Animal Signals: Models and Terminology". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 177 (3): 305–311. Bibcode:1995JThBi.177..305S. doi:10.1006/jtbi.1995.0248. ISSN 0022-5193. S2CID 42856706.
  10. ^ a b c Dawkins, Richard (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-217773-7. OCLC 20012195.
  11. ^ a b Grafen, Alan (2025-08-06). "Biological signals as handicaps". Journal of Theoretical Biology. 144 (4): 517–546. Bibcode:1990JThBi.144..517G. doi:10.1016/S0022-5193(05)80088-8. ISSN 0022-5193. PMID 2402153.
  12. ^ a b c Bliege Bird, Rebecca; Smith, Eric; Bird, Douglas (2025-08-06). "The hunting handicap: costly signaling in human foraging strategies". Behavioral Ecology and Sociobiology. 50 (1): 9–19. doi:10.1007/s002650100338. ISSN 0340-5443. S2CID 14940511.
  13. ^ Cosmides, Leda; Tooby, John (1992). "Cognitive adaptations for social exchange". In Barkow, Jerome; Cosmides, Leda; Tooby, John (eds.). The adapted mind: Evolutionary psychology and the generation of culture. Oxford: Oxford University PRess.
  14. ^ Sugiyama, Lawrence S.; Tooby, John; Cosmides, Leda (2025-08-06). "Cross-cultural evidence of cognitive adaptations for social exchange among the Shiwiar of Ecuadorian Amazonia". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 99 (17): 11537–11542. Bibcode:2002PNAS...9911537S. doi:10.1073/pnas.122352999. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 123291. PMID 12177409.
  15. ^ Boyer, Pascal (2025-08-06). "Why Divination?: Evolved Psychology and Strategic Interaction in the Production of Truth". Current Anthropology. 61 (1): 100–123. doi:10.1086/706879. ISSN 0011-3204. S2CID 210925724.
  16. ^ a b c d Gangestad, Steven W.; Scheyd, Glenn J. (2005). "The Evolution of Human Physical Attractiveness". Annual Review of Anthropology. 34 (1): 523–548. doi:10.1146/annurev.anthro.33.070203.143733. ISSN 0084-6570.
  17. ^ Hooper, Paul L.; Miller, Geoffrey F. (2008). "Mutual Mate Choice Can Drive Costly Signaling Even Under Perfect Monogamy". Adaptive Behavior. 16 (1): 53–70. doi:10.1177/1059712307087283. ISSN 1059-7123. S2CID 18301208.
  18. ^ a b Buss, David M. (1989). "Sex differences in human mate preferences: Evolutionary hypotheses tested in 37 cultures". Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 12 (1): 1–14. doi:10.1017/S0140525X00023992. ISSN 1469-1825.
  19. ^ a b c d Sundie, Jill M.; Kenrick, Douglas T.; Griskevicius, Vladas; Tybur, Joshua M.; Vohs, Kathleen D.; Beal, Daniel J. (2011). "Peacocks, Porsches, and Thorstein Veblen: Conspicuous consumption as a sexual signaling system". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 100 (4): 664–680. doi:10.1037/a0021669. ISSN 1939-1315. PMID 21038972.
  20. ^ a b c d e f Miller, Geoffrey F. (2007). "Sexual Selection for Moral Virtues". The Quarterly Review of Biology. 82 (2): 97–125. doi:10.1086/517857. ISSN 0033-5770. PMID 17583267. S2CID 1021904.
  21. ^ a b c d e f g h Smith, Eric Alden; Bird, Rebecca L. Bliege (2025-08-06). "Turtle hunting and tombstone opening: public generosity as costly signaling". Evolution and Human Behavior. 21 (4): 245–261. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(00)00031-3. ISSN 1090-5138. PMID 10899477.
  22. ^ a b c d e Hawkes, Kristen; Bird, Rebecca Bliege (2002). "Showing off, handicap signaling, and the evolution of men's work". Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews. 11 (2): 58–67. doi:10.1002/evan.20005. ISSN 1520-6505. S2CID 15164689.
  23. ^ Sosis, Richard (2025-08-06). "Costly signaling and torch fishing on Ifaluk atoll". Evolution and Human Behavior. 21 (4): 223–244. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(00)00030-1. ISSN 1090-5138. PMID 10899476.
  24. ^ a b c Hawkes, Kristen (2025-08-06). "Showing off: Tests of an hypothesis about men's foraging goals". Ethology and Sociobiology. 12 (1): 29–54. doi:10.1016/0162-3095(91)90011-E. ISSN 0162-3095.
  25. ^ a b c Gurven, Michael; Hill, Kim (2009). "Why Do Men Hunt?: A Reevaluation of "Man the Hunter" and the Sexual Division of Labor". Current Anthropology. 50 (1): 51–74. doi:10.1086/595620. ISSN 0011-3204. PMID 19579355. S2CID 33909267.
  26. ^ a b Gurven, Michael; von Rueden, Christopher (2006). "Hunting, social status and biological fitness". Biodemography and Social Biology. 53 (1–2): 81–99. doi:10.1080/19485565.2006.9989118. ISSN 1948-5565. PMID 21516952. S2CID 26575043.
  27. ^ a b c d e Gurven, Michael; Allen-Arave, Wesley; Hill, Kim; Hurtado, Magdalena (2000). ""It's a Wonderful Life": signaling generosity among the Ache of Paraguay". Evolution and Human Behavior. 21 (4): 263–282. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(00)00032-5. PMID 10899478.
  28. ^ a b c d e f Wilson, Margo; Daly, Martin (2025-08-06). "Competitiveness, risk taking, and violence: the young male syndrome". Ethology and Sociobiology. 6 (1): 59–73. doi:10.1016/0162-3095(85)90041-X. ISSN 0162-3095. S2CID 9068200.
  29. ^ a b c d e Farthing, G. William (2005). "Attitudes toward heroic and nonheroic physical risk takers as mates and as friends". Evolution and Human Behavior. 26 (2): 171–185. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2004.08.004.
  30. ^ a b c d Baker, Michael D.; Maner, Jon K. (2009). "Male risk-taking as a context-sensitive signaling device". Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 45 (5): 1136–1139. doi:10.1016/j.jesp.2009.06.006.
  31. ^ a b Kelly, S.; Dunbar, R. I. (2001). "Who dares, wins: Heroism versus altruism in women's mate choice". Human Nature. 12 (2). Hawthorne, N.Y.: 89–105. doi:10.1007/s12110-001-1018-6. ISSN 1045-6767. PMID 26192164. S2CID 25044517.
  32. ^ a b c Feinberg, David R. (2025-08-06). "Are human faces and voices ornaments signaling common underlying cues to mate value?". Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews. 17 (2): 112–118. doi:10.1002/evan.20166. S2CID 86168089.
  33. ^ Thornhill, Randy; Gangestad, Steven W. (1999). "Facial attractiveness". Trends in Cognitive Sciences. 3 (12): 452–460. doi:10.1016/S1364-6613(99)01403-5. PMID 10562724. S2CID 961347.
  34. ^ a b Bovet, Jeanne (2025-08-06). "Evolutionary Theories and Men's Preferences for Women's Waist-to-Hip Ratio: Which Hypotheses Remain? A Systematic Review". Frontiers in Psychology. 10: 1221. doi:10.3389/fpsyg.2019.01221. ISSN 1664-1078. PMC 6563790. PMID 31244708.
  35. ^ a b c Hodges-Simeon, Carolyn R.; Gaulin, Steven J. C.; Puts, David A. (2010). "Different Vocal Parameters Predict Perceptions of Dominance and Attractiveness". Human Nature. 21 (4): 406–427. doi:10.1007/s12110-010-9101-5. ISSN 1045-6767. PMC 2995855. PMID 21212816.
  36. ^ a b Hodges-Simeon, Carolyn R.; Gurven, Michael; Gaulin, Steven J. C. (2025-08-06). "The low male voice is a costly signal of phenotypic quality among Bolivian adolescents". Evolution and Human Behavior. 36 (4): 294–302. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.01.002. ISSN 1090-5138.
  37. ^ Fitch, W. Tecumseh; Giedd, Jay (1999). "Morphology and development of the human vocal tract: A study using magnetic resonance imaging". The Journal of the Acoustical Society of America. 106 (3): 1511–1522. Bibcode:1999ASAJ..106.1511F. doi:10.1121/1.427148. ISSN 0001-4966. PMID 10489707. S2CID 13091554.
  38. ^ a b Sugiyama, Lawrence S. (2015). "Physical Attractiveness: An Adaptationist Perspective". The Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology. American Cancer Society. pp. 1–68. doi:10.1002/9781119125563.evpsych112. ISBN 978-1-119-12556-3.
  39. ^ M?ller, Anders Pape (1990). "Parasites and sexual selection: Current status of the Hamilton and Zuk hypothesis". Journal of Evolutionary Biology. 3 (5–6): 319–328. doi:10.1046/j.1420-9101.1990.3050319.x. ISSN 1420-9101. S2CID 31267392.
  40. ^ Reinhold, KLAUS; Greenfield, MICHAEL D.; Jang, YIKWEON; Broce, ALBERTO (2025-08-06). "Energetic cost of sexual attractiveness: ultrasonic advertisement in wax moths". Animal Behaviour. 55 (4): 905–913. doi:10.1006/anbe.1997.0594. ISSN 0003-3472. PMID 9632477. S2CID 22230681.
  41. ^ Zahavi, Amotz (1978). "Decorative patterns and the evolution of art". New Scientist. 80: 182–184.
  42. ^ a b c Miller, Geoffrey F. (2000). The mating mind: how sexual choice shaped the evolution of human nature (1st Anchor Books ed.). New York: Anchor Books. ISBN 0-385-49517-X. OCLC 47923735.
  43. ^ a b c d Miller, Geoffrey F. (2001). "Aesthetic fitness: How sexual selection shaped artistic virtuosity as a fitness indicator and aesthetic preferences as mate choice criteria". Bulletin of Psychology and the Arts. doi:10.1037/e514542010-007.
  44. ^ a b c d e f g h i Miller, G. F. (2016). Art-making evolved mostly to attract mates. In On the origins of art [exhibition catalog] pp. 163-213. Hobart, Tasmania: Museum of Old and New Art.
  45. ^ Seymour, Robert M.; Sozou, Peter D. (2009). "Duration of courtship effort as a costly signal" (PDF). Journal of Theoretical Biology. 256 (1): 1–13. Bibcode:2009JThBi.256....1S. doi:10.1016/j.jtbi.2008.09.026. PMID 18955065.
  46. ^ Buss, David M. (2003). The evolution of desire: strategies of human mating (Rev. ed.). New York: Basic Books. ISBN 0-465-00802-X. OCLC 50782664.
  47. ^ a b c d e Lummaa, Virpi; Vuorisalo, Timo; Barr, Ronald G.; Lehtonen, Liisa (2025-08-06). "Why Cry? Adaptive Significance of Intensive Crying in Human Infants". Evolution and Human Behavior. 19 (3): 193–202. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(98)00014-2. ISSN 1090-5138.
  48. ^ a b c d e f g h Soltis, Joseph (2004). "The signal functions of early infant crying". Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 27 (4): 443–458. doi:10.1017/S0140525X0400010X. ISSN 1469-1825. PMID 15773426. S2CID 25743823.
  49. ^ a b c d e f Furlow, F. Bryant (2025-08-06). "Human Neonatal Cry Quality as an honest signal of fitness". Evolution and Human Behavior. 18 (3): 175–193. doi:10.1016/S1090-5138(97)00006-8. ISSN 1090-5138.
  50. ^ a b c d e f Thornhill, Randy; Furlow, F. Bryant (1998). "Stress and human reproductive behavior: attractiveness, women's sexual development, postpartum depression, and baby's cry.". In M?ller, Anders; Milinski, Manfred; Slater, Peter (eds.). Stress and Behavior. San Diego, CA: Academic Press.
  51. ^ Trivers, Robert (1972). "Parental investment and sexual selection". In Campbell, B. (ed.). Sexual selection and the descent of man. Chicago, IL.: Aldine. ISBN 9780202020051.
  52. ^ a b Hagen, Edward H. (2004). "Is excessive infant crying an honest signal of vigor, one extreme of a continuum, or a strategy to manipulate parents?". Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 27 (4): 463–464. doi:10.1017/S0140525X04270108. ISSN 1469-1825. S2CID 145542180.
  53. ^ a b c Tiokhin, Leonid; Panchanathan, Karthik; Lakens, Daniel; Vazire, Simine; Morgan, Thomas; Zollman, Kevin (23 February 2021). Suen, Wing (ed.). "Honest signaling in academic publishing". PLOS ONE. 16 (2). Public Library of Science (PLoS): e0246675. Bibcode:2021PLoSO..1646675T. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0246675. ISSN 1932-6203. PMC 7901761. PMID 33621261.
  54. ^ a b c d e f g Bliege Bird, Rebecca; Ready, Elspeth; Power, Eleanor A. (2018). "The social significance of subtle signals". Nature Human Behaviour. 2 (7): 452–457. doi:10.1038/s41562-018-0298-3. ISSN 2397-3374. PMID 31097793. S2CID 25103239.
  55. ^ a b c d Gurven, Michael (2004). "To give and to give not: The behavioral ecology of human food transfers". Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 27 (4): 543–559. doi:10.1017/S0140525X04000123. ISSN 1469-1825. S2CID 12150875.
  56. ^ a b Ridley, Matt (1998). The origins of virtue: human instincts and the evolution of cooperation. London: Penguin Books. ISBN 0-14-026445-0. OCLC 38933813.
  57. ^ a b c d e f g Boone, James L. (1998). "The evolution of magnanimity: When is it better to give than to receive?". Human Nature. 9 (1): 1–21. doi:10.1007/s12110-998-1009-y. ISSN 1045-6767. PMID 26197355. S2CID 45198951.
  58. ^ a b Lyle, H. F.; Smith, E. A.; Sullivan, R. J. (2009). "Blood donations as costly signals of donor quality". Journal of Evolutionary Psychology. 7 (4): 263–286. doi:10.1556/JEP.7.2009.4.1. ISSN 1789-2082.
  59. ^ a b c André, Jean‐Baptiste (2010). "The Evolution of Reciprocity: Social Types or Social Incentives?". The American Naturalist. 175 (2): 197–210. doi:10.1086/649597. ISSN 0003-0147. PMID 20014939. S2CID 23954980.
  60. ^ Alexander, Richard D. (1987). The biology of moral systems. Hawthorne, N.Y.: A. de Gruyter. ISBN 0-202-01173-9. OCLC 14359861.
  61. ^ Nowak, Martin A.; Sigmund, Karl (2005). "Evolution of indirect reciprocity". Nature. 437 (7063): 1291–1298. Bibcode:2005Natur.437.1291N. doi:10.1038/nature04131. ISSN 0028-0836. PMID 16251955. S2CID 3153895.
  62. ^ a b c d e f Hruschka, Daniel J. (2010). Friendship: development, ecology, and evolution of a relationship. Berkeley: University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-94788-7. OCLC 669749274.
  63. ^ Komiya, Asuka; Ohtsubo, Yohsuke; Nakanishi, Daisuke; Oishi, Shigehiro (2025-08-06). "Gift-giving in romantic couples serves as a commitment signal: Relational mobility is associated with more frequent gift-giving". Evolution and Human Behavior. 40 (2): 160–166. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2018.10.003. ISSN 1090-5138. S2CID 149744620.
  64. ^ a b Yamaguchi, Mana; Smith, Adam; Ohtsubo, Yohsuke (2025-08-06). "Commitment signals in friendship and romantic relationships". Evolution and Human Behavior. 36 (6): 467–474. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.05.002. hdl:20.500.14094/90003509. ISSN 1090-5138.
  65. ^ a b c d Kimeldorf, Marcia (2005). Gift Giving as Costly Signaling in Courtship Contexts (MA). University of Miami.
  66. ^ a b c Carmichael, H. Lorne; MacLeod, W. Bentley (1997). "Gift Giving and the Evolution of Cooperation". International Economic Review. 38 (3). JSTOR: 485. doi:10.2307/2527277. ISSN 0020-6598. JSTOR 2527277.
  67. ^ a b Camerer, Colin (2025-08-06). "Gifts as Economic Signals and Social Symbols" (PDF). American Journal of Sociology. 94: S180 – S214. doi:10.1086/228946. ISSN 0002-9602. S2CID 50917852.
  68. ^ Legare, Cristine H.; Watson‐Jones, Rachel E. (2015), "The Evolution and Ontogeny of Ritual", The Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology, American Cancer Society, pp. 1–19, doi:10.1002/9781119125563.evpsych234, ISBN 978-1-119-12556-3
  69. ^ a b c Sosis, Richard (2003). "Why aren't we all hutterites?: Costly signaling theory and religious behavior". Human Nature. 14 (2): 91–127. doi:10.1007/s12110-003-1000-6. ISSN 1045-6767. PMID 26190055. S2CID 43018712.
  70. ^ a b Irons, William (2001). "Religion as a hard-to-fake sign of commitment". In Nesse, Randolph (ed.). Evolution and the capacity for commitment. Russell Sage Foundation.
  71. ^ Sosis, Richard; Alcorta, Candace (2025-08-06). "Signaling, solidarity, and the sacred: The evolution of religious behavior". Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews. 12 (6): 264–274. doi:10.1002/evan.10120. S2CID 443130.
  72. ^ a b Norenzayan, Ara; Shariff, Azim F.; Gervais, Will M.; Willard, Aiyana K.; McNamara, Rita A.; Slingerland, Edward; Henrich, Joseph (2016). "The cultural evolution of prosocial religions". Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 39: e1. doi:10.1017/S0140525X14001356. ISSN 0140-525X. PMID 26785995.
  73. ^ a b c Sosis, Richard (2004). "The Adaptive Value of Religious Ritual: Rituals promote group cohesion by requiring members to engage in behavior that is too costly to fake". American Scientist. 92: 166–172. doi:10.1511/2004.46.928.
  74. ^ a b Power, Eleanor A. (2025-08-06). "Collective ritual and social support networks in rural South India". Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences. 285 (1879): 20180023. doi:10.1098/rspb.2018.0023. PMC 5998092. PMID 29794040.
  75. ^ Sosis, Richard; Bressler, Eric R. (2003). "Cooperation and Commune Longevity: A Test of the Costly Signaling Theory of Religion". Cross-Cultural Research. 37 (2): 211–239. doi:10.1177/1069397103037002003. ISSN 1069-3971. S2CID 7908906.
  76. ^ Xygalatas, Dimitris; Mitkidis, Panagiotis; Fischer, Ronald; Reddish, Paul; Skewes, Joshua; Geertz, Armin W.; Roepstorff, Andreas; Bulbulia, Joseph (2013). "Extreme Rituals Promote Prosociality" (PDF). Psychological Science. 24 (8): 1602–1605. doi:10.1177/0956797612472910. ISSN 0956-7976. PMID 23740550. S2CID 43208333.
  77. ^ a b c d Ohtsubo, Yohsuke; Watanabe, Esuka (2009). "Do sincere apologies need to be costly? Test of a costly signaling model of apology" (PDF). Evolution and Human Behavior. 30 (2): 114–123. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2008.09.004.
  78. ^ a b c d Syme, Kristen L.; Hagen, Edward H. (2025-08-06). "When Saying "Sorry" Isn't Enough: Is Some Suicidal Behavior a Costly Signal of Apology?". Human Nature. 30 (1): 117–141. doi:10.1007/s12110-018-9333-3. ISSN 1936-4776. PMID 30552579. S2CID 54613358.
  79. ^ Rosenthal, Robert W. (2025-08-06). "Suicide attempts and signalling games". Mathematical Social Sciences. 26 (1): 25–33. doi:10.1016/0165-4896(93)90009-8. ISSN 0165-4896.
  80. ^ a b Syme, Kristen L.; Garfield, Zachary H.; Hagen, Edward H. (2025-08-06). "Testing the bargaining vs. inclusive fitness models of suicidal behavior against the ethnographic record". Evolution and Human Behavior. 37 (3): 179–192. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2015.10.005. ISSN 1090-5138.
  81. ^ Ohtsubo, Yohsuke; Watanabe, Esuka; Kim, Jiyoon; Kulas, John T.; Muluk, Hamdi; Nazar, Gabriela; Wang, Feixue; Zhang, Jingyu (2012). "Are costly apologies universally perceived as being sincere?" (PDF). Journal of Evolutionary Psychology. 10 (4): 187–204. doi:10.1556/jep.10.2012.4.3. ISSN 1789-2082.
  82. ^ Ohtsubo, Yohsuke; Yagi, Ayano (2025-08-06). "Relationship value promotes costly apology-making: testing the valuable relationships hypothesis from the perpetrator's perspective". Evolution and Human Behavior. 36 (3): 232–239. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2014.11.008. ISSN 1090-5138.
  83. ^ Watanabe, E.; Ohtsubo, Y. (2012). "Costly apology and self-punishment after an unintentional transgression" (PDF). Journal of Evolutionary Psychology. 10 (3): 87–105. doi:10.1556/jep.10.2012.3.1. ISSN 1789-2082.
  84. ^ a b c d Mehr, Samuel A.; Krasnow, Max M. (2025-08-06). "Parent-offspring conflict and the evolution of infant-directed song". Evolution and Human Behavior. 38 (5): 674–684. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2016.12.005. ISSN 1090-5138.
  85. ^ a b c Saad, Gad (2015). "Evolution and Consumer Psychology". The Handbook of Evolutionary Psychology. American Cancer Society. pp. 1–18. doi:10.1002/9781119125563.evpsych250. ISBN 978-1-119-12556-3.
  86. ^ a b c d Nelissen, Rob M.A.; Meijers, Marijn H.C. (2011). "Social benefits of luxury brands as costly signals of wealth and status". Evolution and Human Behavior. 32 (5): 343–355. doi:10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2010.12.002.
  87. ^ a b De Fraja, Gianni (2009). "The origin of utility: Sexual selection and conspicuous consumption" (PDF). Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 72 (1): 51–69. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2009.05.019. S2CID 17910319.
  88. ^ Buss, David M. (2015). Evolutionary psychology: the new science of the mind (5th ed.). Boston. ISBN 978-0-205-99212-6. OCLC 887605467.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  89. ^ Wang, Yajin; Griskevicius, Vladas (2025-08-06). "Conspicuous Consumption, Relationships, and Rivals: Women's Luxury Products as Signals to Other Women". Journal of Consumer Research. 40 (5): 834–854. doi:10.1086/673256. ISSN 0093-5301.
  90. ^ a b Hudders, Liselot; De Backer, Charlotte; Fisher, Maryanne; Vyncke, Patrick (2014). "The Rival Wears Prada: Luxury Consumption as a Female Competition Strategy". Evolutionary Psychology. 12 (3): 570–87. doi:10.1177/147470491401200306. ISSN 1474-7049. PMC 10480915. PMID 25299993.
  91. ^ Griskevicius, Vladas; Tybur, Joshua M.; Sundie, Jill M.; Cialdini, Robert B.; Miller, Geoffrey F.; Kenrick, Douglas T. (2007). "Blatant benevolence and conspicuous consumption: When romantic motives elicit strategic costly signals". Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 93 (1): 85–102. doi:10.1037/0022-3514.93.1.85. ISSN 1939-1315. PMID 17605591.
  92. ^ a b c d e f g Hagen, Edward (2003). "The Bargaining Model of Depression". In Hammerstein, Peter (ed.). Genetic and Cultural Evolution of Cooperation. The MIT Press. ISBN 0-262-08326-4.
  93. ^ a b c d e Steinkopf, Leander (2015). "The Signaling Theory of Symptoms: An Evolutionary Explanation of the Placebo Effect". Evolutionary Psychology. 13 (3): 147470491560055. doi:10.1177/1474704915600559. ISSN 1474-7049. PMC 10480909.
  94. ^ a b Tiokhin, Leonid (2016). "Do Symptoms of Illness Serve Signaling Functions? (Hint: Yes)". The Quarterly Review of Biology. 91 (2): 177–195. doi:10.1086/686811. ISSN 0033-5770. PMID 27405223. S2CID 25776913.
  95. ^ a b c Hasson, Oren (2009). "Emotional Tears as Biological Signals". Evolutionary Psychology. 7 (3): 147470490900700. doi:10.1177/147470490900700302. ISSN 1474-7049.
  96. ^ a b c Zeifman, Debra M; St James-Roberts, Ian (2017). "Parenting the crying infant". Current Opinion in Psychology. 15: 149–154. doi:10.1016/j.copsyc.2017.02.009. PMC 5494986. PMID 28685155.
  97. ^ Barr, Ronald G. (1990). "The early crying paradox: A modest proposal". Human Nature. 1 (4): 355–389. doi:10.1007/BF02734051. ISSN 1045-6767. PMID 24222175. S2CID 34733149.
  98. ^ Syme, Kristen L.; Hagen, Edward H. (2020). "Mental health is biological health: Why tackling "diseases of the mind" is an imperative for biological anthropology in the 21st century". American Journal of Physical Anthropology. 170 (S70): 87–117. doi:10.1002/ajpa.23965. ISSN 1096-8644. PMID 31762015.
  99. ^ Hendriks, Michelle C. P.; Vingerhoets, Ad J. J. M. (2006). "Social messages of crying faces: Their influence on anticipated person perception, emotions and behavioural responses". Cognition & Emotion. 20 (6): 878–886. doi:10.1080/02699930500450218. ISSN 0269-9931. S2CID 15976145.
  100. ^ a b c Vingerhoets, Ad J. J. M.; van de Ven, Niels; van der Velden, Yvonne (2016). "The social impact of emotional tears". Motivation and Emotion. 40 (3): 455–463. doi:10.1007/s11031-016-9543-0. ISSN 0146-7239. PMC 4882350. PMID 27340307.
  101. ^ Hendriks, Michelle C. P.; Croon, Marcel A.; Vingerhoets, Ad J. J. M. (2008). "Social Reactions to Adult Crying: The Help-Soliciting Function of Tears". The Journal of Social Psychology. 148 (1): 22–42. doi:10.3200/SOCP.148.1.22-42. ISSN 0022-4545. PMID 18476481. S2CID 32992866.
射手是什么星象 煮肉放什么调料 水过鸭背是什么意思 三个马读什么 鱼豆腐是用什么做的
黑白猫是什么品种 南瓜什么季节成熟 鳞状上皮内高度病变是什么意思 鸡属相和什么属相最配 出淤泥而不染是什么意思
口腔溃疡吃什么 牙龈发黑是什么原因 美国绿卡有什么好处 结婚60年是什么婚 泌尿道感染吃什么药
白菜什么时候种 37属什么 手指头发麻是什么原因引起的 阴道炎吃什么药 小孩上户口需要什么材料
孕妇适合吃什么食物hcv7jop9ns3r.cn 梦见西红柿是什么预兆sscsqa.com 尿酸高吃什么蔬菜好zsyouku.com 脾虚湿气重吃什么药hcv9jop2ns7r.cn 弹性工作制是什么意思ff14chat.com
做手术后吃什么对伤口恢复快hcv7jop9ns3r.cn 违心的话是什么意思hcv8jop5ns9r.cn 坐围是什么hcv8jop6ns3r.cn andy是什么意思hcv9jop2ns1r.cn 马铃薯什么时候传入中国hcv7jop9ns7r.cn
乳糖不耐受吃什么奶粉好hcv8jop3ns3r.cn 吉星高照是什么生肖hcv9jop5ns2r.cn 1963年的兔是什么命1949doufunao.com 菜场附近开什么店好hcv9jop5ns7r.cn 为什么男人喜欢邓文迪jingluanji.com
深圳为什么叫鹏城hcv8jop9ns2r.cn 结膜出血是什么原因hcv7jop5ns0r.cn 什么是免疫治疗hcv9jop7ns1r.cn 什么话是世界通用的bfb118.com 自贸区什么意思hcv8jop3ns5r.cn
百度